欢迎来到冰点文库! | 帮助中心 分享价值,成长自我!
冰点文库
全部分类
  • 临时分类>
  • IT计算机>
  • 经管营销>
  • 医药卫生>
  • 自然科学>
  • 农林牧渔>
  • 人文社科>
  • 工程科技>
  • PPT模板>
  • 求职职场>
  • 解决方案>
  • 总结汇报>
  • ImageVerifierCode 换一换
    首页 冰点文库 > 资源分类 > DOCX文档下载
    分享到微信 分享到微博 分享到QQ空间

    外商直接投资和技术溢出泰国制造业的一个跨行业分析论文外文翻译中英文论文对照翻译Word下载.docx

    • 资源ID:4526935       资源大小:22.99KB        全文页数:9页
    • 资源格式: DOCX        下载积分:3金币
    快捷下载 游客一键下载
    账号登录下载
    微信登录下载
    三方登录下载: 微信开放平台登录 QQ登录
    二维码
    微信扫一扫登录
    下载资源需要3金币
    邮箱/手机:
    温馨提示:
    快捷下载时,用户名和密码都是您填写的邮箱或者手机号,方便查询和重复下载(系统自动生成)。
    如填写123,账号就是123,密码也是123。
    支付方式: 支付宝    微信支付   
    验证码:   换一换

    加入VIP,免费下载
     
    账号:
    密码:
    验证码:   换一换
      忘记密码?
        
    友情提示
    2、PDF文件下载后,可能会被浏览器默认打开,此种情况可以点击浏览器菜单,保存网页到桌面,就可以正常下载了。
    3、本站不支持迅雷下载,请使用电脑自带的IE浏览器,或者360浏览器、谷歌浏览器下载即可。
    4、本站资源下载后的文档和图纸-无水印,预览文档经过压缩,下载后原文更清晰。
    5、试题试卷类文档,如果标题没有明确说明有答案则都视为没有答案,请知晓。

    外商直接投资和技术溢出泰国制造业的一个跨行业分析论文外文翻译中英文论文对照翻译Word下载.docx

    1、 541-556中文3087字毕业论文(设计)外文翻译一、外文原文Foreign direct investment and Technology Spillover: ACross-industry Analysis of Thai ManufacturingForeign direct investment (FDI) has been widely recognized as a growth-enhancing factor in investment receiving (host) countries. FDI not only brings in capital but also

    2、 introduces advanced technology that can enhance the technological capability of the host country firms, thereby generating long-term and sustainable economic growth. More importantly, the technological benefit is not limited to locally affiliated firms but can also spread to non-affiliated ones. Th

    3、e latter benefit is usually referred to as technology spillover.The expectation of gaining from technology spillover persuades many developing countries to offer various incentives in order to attract FDI. However the results of empirical research to test the validity of technology spillover are far

    4、 from conclusive. Positive technology spillover from FDI has only been found in some countries.1 Overall, the findings seem to suggest technology spillover is not automatic, but depends on both country specific factors and policy environment.Foreign Presence in Thai ManufacturingThirdly, foreign pla

    5、nts are likely to be located in a highly protected industry. The average ERP2 of industries whose output shares of foreign plants are greater than 50% is 15.3%. The exception in these industries would be electrical machinery which is presumably dominated by labor-intensive assembled electronics and

    6、electrical appliances. On the other hand, regarding the industries where the share of foreign plants is less than 50%, average ERP tends to be lower at around 10.8%. In addition, the output share of foreign plants is likely to be associated with the degree of market concentration.Involvement of fore

    7、ign plants in the manufacturing sector was predominately in import substituting industries such as textiles, automobiles, and chemicals up to about the late 1970s (Akira, 1989). From then on, it was directed to more export-oriented activities. To begin with, export-oriented foreign firms entered lig

    8、ht manufacturing industries such as clothing, footwear, and toys. More recently, labor-intensive assembly activities in electronics and electrical goods industries have been the main attraction for foreign investors (Kohpaiboon, 2005).Such involvement has closely mirrored the shift in the trade poli

    9、cy regime. Thailand began its first national economic development plan in 1961 with an import substitution (IS) regime to promote industrialization. Tariffs were the major instrument used to influence the countrys development path. The role of tariffs to promote the domestic industry effectively beg

    10、an in 1974 with the imposition of an escalating tariff structure, where the tariff rate ascended from raw materials to finished products. These changes increasingly favored the production of finished products, particularly consumer products. In 1975, the range of the effective rate of protection (ER

    11、P) in the Thai manufacturing sector was between 36 to 350% (Akrasanee & Ajanant, 1986). In 1982, the variation widened from 25.2 to 1,693.4% (Chunanantathum et al. 1984). Several industries, such as textiles, tyres, furniture, automobiles, and leather products, had an extremely high ERP. There was a

    12、lso a high degree of variation in ERP across industries. This tariff structure remained virtually unchanged until the late 1980s, even though in 1974 the government announced a change in development strategy to an export promotion (EP) regime.Significant tariff reductions commenced in 1988, starting

    13、 with electrical and electronic goods as well as with the inputs into these products. Comprehensive packages of tariff reform were implemented in 1995 and 1997. It involved tariff reduction and rationalization. Maximum tariffs were reduced from 100% in the early 1990s to 30%. By the end of the 1990s

    14、, the tariff bands were reduced from 39 to 6 tariff rates (0, 1, 5, 10, 20 and 30%). The two low rates (0 and 1%) were for raw materials and the two top rates (20 and 30%) for finished products with the two middle rates for intermediate goods. In addition, tariff restructuring has received renewed e

    15、mphasis as an essential part of the overall economic reforms aimed at strengthening efficiency and competitiveness over the past two years. The Thai government introduced another effort to lower tariff rates, commencing in June 2003 (implemented in October 2003), followed by a fouryear period of tar

    16、iff reduction from 2004 to 2008. There are around 900 items involved in the second round of tariff reductions, covering a wide range of manufacturing products. The tariff reduction in this round is mainly on intermediate products, thereby maintaining the escalating tariff structure. The magnitude of

    17、 tariff reduction is moderate, within the range of 0 to8.9% (Athukorala et al. 2004).As a result, average tariffs declined markedly from 30.2% in 1990 to 21.3% in 1995 and further to 11% in 2005. The dispersion of ERP also narrowed over the periods across industries. In 2003, the ERP range reduced t

    18、o -27.1 to 142% (Athukorala et al. 2004).4 The changes in the tariff structure would have significantly improved the incentive to attract FDI to industries where Thailand has a comparative advantage in international production.Analytical FrameworkTechnology spillover from FDI is said to take place w

    19、hen the presence of a foreign firm generates productivity or efficiency benefits for the host countrys local non-affiliated firms (Blomstrm & Kokko,1998). As mentioned, technology spillover from FDI is not automatic but rather conditioned on the nature of the trade policy regime across industries. A

    20、 theoretical framework for examining the effect of the trade policy regime on the gains from FDI in a given host country was first presented by Bhagwati (1973) as an extension to his theory of immiserizing growth. It was further developed by Bhagwati (1985, 1994); Brecher & Diaz-Alejandro (1977); an

    21、d Brecher & Findlay (1983). A key hypothesis arising from this literature is that technology spillover tends to be smaller, or possibly even negative, under a restrictive, import substitution (IS) regime compared with a liberalizing, export promotion (EP) regime.To illustrate how technology spillove

    22、r takes place as well as how the trade policy regime across industries can alter the magnitude of these spillovers as suggested by Bhagwati (1973), we use the theoretical model developed by Wang & Blomstrm (1992). In the model, there are two firms, namely an affiliate of a multinational enterprise (

    23、MNE) and a local non-affiliated firm (henceforth referred to as the foreign and local firms, respectively), producing differentiated but substitutable products for the host country market. Technology spillover is an outcome of interaction of these two firms. On the one hand, the entry of a foreign f

    24、irm is always associated with some amount of proprietary technology from the parent company so as to offset the potential disadvantage against the local firm possessing superior knowledge of the availability of factor inputs, business practices and/or consumer preferences in the host country. In add

    25、ition, advanced technology would help the foreign firm to gain market share in the host country. However transferring technology from MNEs headquarter to its affiliates are costly. The more the advance level of technology transferred, the larger the dollar costs associated with the transfer.Because

    26、of the presence of cost and benefit, the foreign firm has to decide the effort of undertaking technology transferred from its headquarter to maximize its net benefit. Such effort would depend on the local firms response to the presence of the foreign firm. In a situation where the local firm activel

    27、y puts in the effort to learn the advanced technology associated with the foreign firm, the technology superiority of the latter will not last long. As the result, it will need to keep undertaking technology transfer activities in the following period in order to maintain the advantage or even to ju

    28、st survive in the host country environment. In contrast, a situation where the local firm is less responsive in attempting to learn the associated technology provides relatively less incentive for the foreign firm to continue to actively undertake technology transfers from its parent company.On the

    29、other hand, the local firm can observe, learn, and adapt superior technology associated with the foreign firm to enhance its own technological capability. This is because the technology accompanied with the foreign firm has certain public good qualities, which cannot be fully internalized, thus the

    30、localization of the foreign firm could potentially generate positive externality in terms of technological benefit to the local firm. Since the market success of each firm depends on the level of technology it employs, this encourages the local firm to learn the associated superior technology. Never

    31、theless, the effort of learning and adapting the associated technology is associated with the dollar amount of cost so that the local firm has to decide its effort to learn associated advanced technology. Similar to the foreign firm, the learning effort of the local firm also depends on the foreign

    32、firm behavior.To incorporate the Bhagwati hypothesis, the model discussed above is modified by hypothesizing that the trade policy regime influences the cost effectiveness in the learning activities of the local firm. That is, every effort to enhance the technological capability of the local firm is more costly in any industry where the trade regime is more restrictive. This is because much of the FDI flowing to an industry with high trade restrictions often enters relatively capital- and skill-intensive products where output is mainly supplied for a highly protected


    注意事项

    本文(外商直接投资和技术溢出泰国制造业的一个跨行业分析论文外文翻译中英文论文对照翻译Word下载.docx)为本站会员主动上传,冰点文库仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知冰点文库(点击联系客服),我们立即给予删除!

    温馨提示:如果因为网速或其他原因下载失败请重新下载,重复下载不扣分。




    关于我们 - 网站声明 - 网站地图 - 资源地图 - 友情链接 - 网站客服 - 联系我们

    copyright@ 2008-2023 冰点文库 网站版权所有

    经营许可证编号:鄂ICP备19020893号-2


    收起
    展开